Key Takeaways
1. Government Health Care Is Inherently Inefficient
Alas, these advocates of “universal care” have fallen victim to one of the most pervasive myths in America today—that government-run health care is effective and efficient.
Government as middleman. Contrary to popular belief, government intervention often complicates processes and increases costs, rather than simplifying them. The idea that a single government producer would be more efficient than multiple private "middlemen" is a fallacy, as evidenced by other government-run services.
- IRS: Does it make paying taxes simpler?
- Government-run schools: Do they provide the best K-12 education?
- Existing health regulations: Do they make healthcare better and more efficient?
Hidden administrative costs. Official estimates often understate the true administrative costs of government programs like Medicare, which appear low (1.5%) compared to private insurance (25%). However, these estimates exclude significant hidden costs, such as salaries of managers, marketing, and the substantial administrative burden shifted onto private providers.
- Medicare's true administrative costs: Around 5.2%
- Private sector's true administrative costs: Around 8.9%
- Private health care premiums: 86% goes to actual medical care.
Price controls fail. The notion that government, as a single payer, can negotiate lower prices is historically flawed. Price controls, from ancient Rome to the Soviet Union, consistently lead to unintended consequences like black markets, reduced quality, and stifled innovation. In healthcare, this directly impacts the development of new, life-saving drugs, which require massive R&D investment.
- Drug R&D: Averages $1.3 billion per drug.
- Government price controls: Caused $188 billion in lost R&D spending since 1960, potentially costing 140 million life-years.
2. High Health Care Spending Reflects Value, Not Waste
What Chad understands instinctively is that words like “cost” and “value” can’t simply be measured in dollars.
Value over cost. While U.S. healthcare spending has dramatically increased (from 5% to 16% of GDP since 1950), this rise reflects a significant increase in value, not just inflated costs. Modern medicine offers life-saving treatments and technologies that simply didn't exist decades ago, like advanced cardiac care or cancer therapies.
- Life expectancy: Increased by almost nine years since 1950.
- Heart disease death rate: Reduced by 59% from 1950-2000.
Investing in longevity. Economists have attempted to quantify the value of these health improvements. Studies suggest that longevity gains from medical innovations are worth trillions annually, far exceeding the direct costs. This indicates that increased spending on healthcare is a rational choice as society becomes wealthier and prioritizes health and extended life.
- Longevity gains: Valued at $2.8 trillion annually.
- 1% reduction in cancer mortality: Valued at $500 billion.
Affordable for most. Despite the alarmist rhetoric, the average American family spends a relatively small portion of its income on healthcare (5.4%) compared to housing (40.8%) or transportation (18.3%). The perception of "too expensive" often stems from indirect payment through employers, obscuring the true value received. As incomes rise, people naturally choose to spend more on health, viewing it as a worthwhile investment in quality of life.
3. The "Uninsured Crisis" Is Grossly Misrepresented
While it’s not technically wrong to say that there are roughly 45.7 million uninsured, it’s grossly misleading to use this number as an indication of a crisis.
Misleading statistics. The widely cited figure of "46 million uninsured Americans" is often used to suggest a widespread crisis, but it's based on a Census Bureau survey that admits to underreporting and only captures a snapshot in time. Many counted as "uninsured" are only temporarily without coverage, often in transition between jobs.
Who are the "uninsured"? A closer look reveals that a significant portion of this group is not struggling to afford care.
- Voluntarily uninsured: Almost 18 million earn over $50,000/year; nearly 10 million earn over $75,000/year. Many young, healthy individuals choose not to buy insurance, preferring to save or spend their money elsewhere.
- Non-citizens: Over 10 million of the "uninsured" are not U.S. citizens.
- Eligible but unenrolled: Up to 14 million are eligible for existing government programs like Medicare, Medicaid, or SCHIP but haven't enrolled, often due to paperwork or lack of awareness.
Focus on the truly needy. The actual number of chronically uninsured working poor who genuinely need assistance is closer to eight million. These individuals earn too much for welfare but too little for private insurance. The solution for this group should focus on making straightforward, catastrophic coverage affordable, rather than expanding complex government bureaucracies that many already eligible individuals fail to utilize.
4. Expensive Drugs Actually Reduce Overall Health Care Costs
In reality, prescription drugs reduce medical spending.
Drugs combat chronic disease. While prescription drug spending is substantial, it's a critical investment that ultimately reduces overall healthcare costs. Chronic diseases, like diabetes and heart disease, account for 85% of U.S. healthcare spending. Drugs effectively manage these conditions, preventing more expensive interventions like hospitalizations and surgeries.
- Chronic disease prevalence: 6 in 10 Americans have at least one.
- Impact of drugs: Every $1 spent on blood pressure, cholesterol, and diabetes drugs saves $4-$7 in other medical spending.
High R&D costs. The high price of new drugs is not primarily due to greed but to the enormous cost and risk of research and development. For every successful drug, thousands of compounds fail, and the approval process takes 10-15 years and averages $1.3 billion per drug. Companies need to recoup these investments to continue innovation.
- Success rate: Only 1 in 5,000-10,000 compounds makes it to market.
- Profitability: Only 2 in 10 approved drugs earn enough to cover R&D.
Innovation drives savings. The U.S. leads the world in pharmaceutical innovation, producing cutting-edge treatments that extend lives and improve quality of life. Despite rising overall drug spending, drug prices are actually falling, largely due to the proliferation of cheaper generic drugs driven by free-market competition. Punishing drug companies with price controls would stifle this innovation, leading to fewer life-saving breakthroughs and ultimately higher overall healthcare costs as more people require expensive, late-stage interventions.
5. Importing Drugs Is a Dangerous Illusion, Not a Solution
Unfortunately, things aren’t always as they seem—and a closer look at the facts reveals that the promise of importation falls dangerously short of the reality.
Foreign price controls. The primary reason some brand-name drugs are cheaper overseas is that foreign governments impose strict price controls to sustain their socialized healthcare systems. This often means delaying or denying access to newer, more expensive, and often more effective drugs.
- Canada: Patented Medicine Prices Review Board strictly monitors drug prices.
- Result: Many cutting-edge drugs available in the U.S. are not approved or are rationed in Canada and Europe.
Not always cheaper. While specific brand-name drugs might be cheaper abroad, the majority of drugs consumed in the U.S. are generics, which are significantly cheaper in the U.S. due to a flourishing free market and competition. The "cheaper abroad" argument applies to a narrow category of price-controlled brand-name drugs.
Threat to innovation. Legalizing drug importation, especially with "forced sale" provisions, would effectively impose foreign price controls on U.S. pharmaceutical companies. This would undermine the profit incentive for R&D, leading to a drastic reduction in new drug development.
- HHS estimates: Importation could cause 4-18 fewer drugs developed per decade.
- Global impact: U.S. firms are responsible for almost 90% of new drugs worldwide.
- Cost savings: Congressional Budget Office estimates only a 1% reduction in national drug expenditure over the next decade from importation.
6. Mandating Universal Coverage Fails to Solve Core Problems
To believe that universal health care coverage can be achieved through a legal mandate is to misunderstand how people react to do-good laws and why.
People resist mandates. Forcing individuals to buy health insurance, as seen with car insurance mandates, does not guarantee universal coverage. Many people, especially healthy young adults, rationally choose not to purchase expensive, comprehensive policies that don't fit their needs, even if it means facing fines.
- Car insurance: Mandatory in most states, yet nearly 15% of drivers are uninsured.
- Massachusetts mandate: 168,000 adults remained uninsured in 2007, with 97,000 able to afford it but choosing not to.
Economic disincentives. Mandates on businesses, forcing them to provide insurance or pay into a state fund, depress economic growth. These "pay or play" schemes increase overhead, discourage new business creation, and can lead to job losses, as companies struggle to absorb the significant expense.
Costly and ineffective. The Massachusetts mandate, despite bipartisan support, saw costs skyrocket far beyond predictions (e.g., Commonwealth Care costing $869 million in FY2009 vs. $125 million predicted). It also failed to achieve true universal coverage, with many exemptions and continued uninsured populations. Mandates also ignore the root cause of high insurance costs: excessive government regulations and benefit mandates that force consumers to buy one-size-fits-all policies covering unnecessary services.
7. Government Prevention Programs Don't Cut Costs and Limit Freedom
But, as a matter of fact, government-financed attempts to make us healthier rarely do anything to reduce national health care costs.
Ineffective interventions. Politicians often promote government-funded prevention programs (e.g., anti-smoking campaigns, trans fat bans) with the promise of reducing healthcare costs. However, evidence shows these initiatives are often unsuccessful, based on shoddy research, and can even have unintended negative consequences.
- Nutrition labeling: Since mandated in 1994, obesity rates have increased by two-thirds.
- Smoking bans: May increase smoking among young people due to "norm backlash."
Prevention increases long-term costs. Counterintuitively, successful prevention programs that lead to healthier, longer lives often increase overall healthcare spending. Older individuals require more expensive late-life care for conditions like Alzheimer's, osteoarthritis, and cancer.
- Healthy nonsmokers: Cost, on average, $100,000 more in medical spending than smokers who die younger.
- Research: "Obesity prevention is not a cure for increasing health expenditures."
Infringement on freedom. Beyond the financial implications, government prevention programs represent an overreach into personal choices. From saltshaker regulations to forced nutritional disclosures, these measures erode individual liberty by attempting to control personal habits through legislation, echoing the failures of historical prohibition movements.
8. Existing Government Aid for the Poor Is Substandard and Unsustainable
In reality, truly poor Americans are already insured by the government. And those who aren’t insured simply haven’t enrolled in existing government programs.
Coverage exists. The argument that more government is needed to insure the poor overlooks the fact that most truly poor Americans are already eligible for or covered by existing government programs like Medicaid and SCHIP. Hospitals are also legally required to treat anyone in an emergency, regardless of insurance status.
- Medicaid: Covers 53 million Americans, exceeding the 37 million estimated to be in poverty.
- Uninsured children: 70% are eligible for Medicaid or SCHIP but not enrolled.
Substandard care. Despite its massive scale and cost ($338 billion in 2006), Medicaid provides substandard care. Low reimbursement rates force many doctors to refuse Medicaid patients, leading to reliance on expensive emergency rooms for non-emergencies and "Medicaid mills" that offer marginal care.
- Doctor acceptance: Only 69.5% of primary care physicians accept new Medicaid patients, compared to 90%+ for private insurance.
- Patient outcomes: Medicaid patients with heart attacks are less likely to receive immediate care and more likely to die.
Unsustainable and fraudulent. Medicaid costs are spiraling out of control, threatening to bankrupt state governments (e.g., Florida projected to spend 60% of its budget by 2015). The program is also plagued by rampant fraud and misuse of funds, estimated to consume at least 10% of outlays. Furthermore, "moral hazard" encourages middle-class individuals to intentionally deplete assets to qualify for "free" long-term care, diverting resources from the truly needy.
9. Health Information Technology Isn't a Magic Bullet for Cost Reduction
Unfortunately, you can’t legislate technological innovation.
Overstated savings. While Health Information Technology (HIT) holds promise for improving efficiency, quality, and safety in healthcare, its potential for cost reduction is often exaggerated by politicians. A RAND Corporation study, frequently cited for its $77 billion annual savings estimate, represents only 3.3% of total U.S. healthcare spending, a modest figure relative to the massive investment required.
High implementation costs. The upfront costs of implementing comprehensive HIT systems are enormous for hospitals (e.g., $150-$300 million for large centers) and individual practices ($40,000-$60,000). These significant expenditures must be weighed against other critical investments in patient care, and government subsidies can distort these decisions, leading to misallocated resources.
- Hospital adoption: Only 5% of hospitals and 10% of doctors had fully switched to electronic records by late 2006.
- Government lag: Only 19% of state health care systems use electronic medical records, compared to 54% of private hospitals.
Government hinders innovation. Government attempts to "create" technological revolutions often result in regulatory messes and stifle true innovation. The 1996 HIPAA law, intended to create portable electronic health records, failed to deliver on its promise. Instead of government-led initiatives, private companies like Microsoft and Google, with proven track records in IT innovation, are better positioned to develop effective and desired HIT solutions by responding to market demands.
10. Foreign Government Systems Are Not Superior or Cheaper
Because the truth is exactly the reverse. It is government monopoly health care that is heartless and uncaring.
Rationing is the reality. Claims that foreign government-run healthcare systems are "better and cheaper" are misleading. While they may spend less, this often comes at the cost of rationing care, leading to long waiting lists, limited access to specialists, and restricted availability of cutting-edge drugs and technology.
- Canada: Over 800,000 citizens on waiting lists for surgery; average wait from referral to specialist is over 18 weeks.
- Britain (NHS): Over 1 million Britons waiting for hospital admission; 200,000 waiting to get on a waiting list.
Inferior outcomes and access. Despite lower spending, these systems often yield inferior patient outcomes for serious conditions compared to the U.S. They also control costs by paying doctors significantly less, leading to physician shortages and reliance on foreign-trained medical graduates.
- U.S. cancer survival: Better for 13 of 16 common cancers compared to Europe/Canada.
- Doctor salaries: Average Canadian doctor earns 42% of U.S. counterpart; German doctors earn $56,455, French $55,000.
Misleading statistics. Crude indicators like infant mortality and life expectancy, often cited to criticize U.S. healthcare, are influenced by many factors beyond healthcare quality, such as homicide rates, accidents, diet, and differing statistical definitions. When these confounding factors are accounted for, U.S. outcomes for those who don't die from external causes are often superior. The U.S. also leads the world in medical research and development, shouldering the burden of innovation that other countries free-ride on through price controls.
11. Market-Based Reforms Offer the Real Path to Better Health Care
But true reform of the health care system requires less government interference—not more.
Embrace the Lasik model. The Lasik eye surgery market demonstrates the power of free-market principles in healthcare. Because it's largely unregulated and not covered by insurance, it features constant technological advancement, fierce price competition, and consumer-driven satisfaction, leading to a nearly 40% price drop in a decade. Expanding this model to other areas is key.
Key market-based solutions:
- Change the Tax Code: Allow individuals the same pre-tax benefits for health insurance that employers currently receive (e.g., refundable tax credits or deductions). This would increase price transparency, empower consumers, and foster competition among insurers.
- Reduce Costly Mandates: Eliminate excessive state-level benefit mandates (e.g., massage therapy, hair prosthesis) that inflate insurance premiums by up to 50% and limit affordable, tailored policy options.
- Allow Interstate Insurance Purchase: Remove state regulatory walls that prevent consumers from buying more affordable insurance plans across state lines, fostering competition and driving down costs.
- Expand Health Savings Accounts (HSAs): Reduce regulations and raise contribution limits for HSAs, which empower individuals with tax-free savings for routine care and high-deductible catastrophic insurance, promoting cost-consciousness and personal control.
- Support Retail Health Clinics: Resist calls from traditional medical establishments to ban or over-regulate retail clinics (e.g., in Wal-Mart, CVS). These clinics offer affordable, convenient, walk-in care (around $50/visit) and are particularly beneficial for the uninsured.
- Implement Tort Reform: Control medical malpractice lawsuits, which drive up costs through high insurance premiums for doctors and defensive medicine practices. Capping non-economic damages and allowing periodic payments would reduce this $124 billion drain on the system.
- Provide Vouchers for the Working Poor: For those genuinely unable to afford insurance (the chronically ill, working poor above welfare limits, veterans), implement a system of insurance vouchers. This ensures coverage without expanding government bureaucracy, allowing recipients to choose private plans or high-risk state pools.
Freedom over control. The choice for American healthcare reform is stark: either expand government control, leading to higher taxes, mandates, rationing, and stifled innovation, or embrace market freedom, consumer choice, and innovation to achieve truly affordable, high-quality, and accessible care for all.
Last updated:
Review Summary
The Top Ten Myths of American Health Care receives mixed reviews, with an average rating of 3.58 out of 5. Readers appreciate the broad overview of healthcare issues and the author's explanations of statistics. Some find it helpful for understanding the current healthcare debate, while others praise its factual content and citations. Critics note that certain points could have been explored more deeply. Overall, readers recommend it for those interested in American healthcare, describing it as a quick read with valuable information on the topic.
Download PDF
Download EPUB
.epub
digital book format is ideal for reading ebooks on phones, tablets, and e-readers.